National Academies Press: OpenBook

Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography (2013)

Chapter: Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums

« Previous: Appendix D: Regression Model Specifications with "Clusters" of Predictors
Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×

Appendix E
Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums

HARVARD INPUT-PRICE ADJUSTMENT MEMORANDUM (11.04.11)

Background

The input price adjustment is meant to reflect variation in input prices required to provide care. Harvard uses input price indices developed by the Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS) to adjust raw spending.

The input price adjustment is performed separately for each of two claim types: (1) inpatient facility diagnosis-related groups (DRGs) and (2) inpatient professional current professional terminologies (CPTs) and outpatient CPTs. The specifications for each are described below, but for each the unit of analysis is the “claim-day.” A “claim-day” is an aggregation of all spending for a given person for a given procedure code for a given claim type (DRG, inpatient CPT, outpatient CPT). For example, a person may have multiple claims for a given code on a given day. We add up the spending for all of the claims for that person for the same code and claim type on the same date (in the case of inpatient stay, we use the admission date) to calculate average spending for the code. For around 15 percent of medical (nondrug) spending, there is an outpatient claim line that is missing a CPT code. For these claims we distribute the spending over claims that do have a CPT on the same day and for the same person according to the proportion of total daily spending each CPT represents. We believe that the outpatient claims that are missing a CPT code are facility payments that have been carved out of the professional payments, and that this procedure

Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×

reapportions spending. For the purpose of input price adjustment, we treat claims that are missing a CPT code and that do not have any CPT codes on the same day as if they were an inpatient facility claim.

Inpatient Facility (DRGs)

Each claim day with a DRG code is adjusted by the Area Wage Index Values that include the occupational mix adjustment.1 The wage index data is merged into MarketScan data by county. 69.7% of the claim amount is adjusted by the wage index value, a proportion based on the labor-related share outlined in the Hospital Inpatient Prospective Payment System Final rule.2 This is the same procedure we perform on any outpatient claims that cannot be apportioned as described above.

(0.697 × raw claim day amount / wage index) + 0.303 × raw claim day amount

Inpatient Professional and Outpatient Claims (CPTs)

Each claim day with a CPT code is adjusted by the fully-implemented relative value unit (RVU)3 share multiplied by the relevant GPCI.4 Inpatient professional and outpatient claims incorporate the practice expense facility component of the RVU.

Raw claim day amount / (%Work × Work GPCI + %PE (facility) * PE GPCI + %MP × MP GPCI)

All other claim types (claims without a valid CPT that cannot be allocated to other claims on the same day, durable medical equipment, prescription drugs) are left unadjusted.

_________________

1The wage index file for 2007 can be found at http://www.cms.gov/AcuteInpatientPPS/WIFN/itemdetail.asp?filterType=none&filterByDID=0&sortByDID=3&sortOrder=ascending&itemID=CMS1187403&intNumPerPage=10.

2The final rule for fiscal year 2007 can be found at http://www.cms.gov/AcuteInpatientPPS/IPPS/itemdetail.asp?filterType=none&filterByDID=-99&sortByDID=4&sortOrder=ascending&itemID=CMS1229138&intNumPerPage=10.

3The RVU lists are based on the October release for each year. 2007 can be found at http://www.cms.gov/PhysicianFeeSched/PFSRVF/itemdetail.asp?filterType=none&filterByDID=-99&sortByDID=1&sortOrder=descending&itemID=CMS1203203&intNumPerPage=1.

4The GPCI lists are based on the October release for each year. 2007 can be found at http://www.cms.gov/PhysicianFeeSched/PFSRVF/itemdetail.asp?filterType=none&filterByDID=-99&sortByDID=1&sortOrder=descending&itemID=CMS1203203&intNumPerPage=10.

Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×

Capitated Claims

We outline our overall approach to capitated claims in a separate memo. We will input-price adjust the imputed values for capitated claims.

Aggregation

After the spending is adjusted as described above, the adjusted spending (including spending on claims that are left unadjusted) is summed across a person-year. This results in one input-price adjusted value per person per year.

HARVARD CLAIM-DAY METHOD MEMORANDUM (11.04.11)

Background

There are frequent occurrences of multiple claims for a single procedure coded on a single day for a single person. This is due to the way claims are coded by providers and processed by insurers. We believe the vast majority of these claims are not separate events, but a single event coded on multiple claim lines. In addition, about 14 percent of total medical spending (non-drug) has no associated CPT code. The vast majority (>95 percent) of this spending is represented in the outpatient facility file. After exploring these claims with experts at Thomson Reuters, we believe that the majority are facility fees carved out of outpatient claims.

Harvard’s Approach

The general approach is to collapse all claims for a specific service (e.g., CPT code), performed on the same day for the same enrollee to 1 claim-day observation. This is the unit of quantity that will be used throughout much of the analysis, such as creating price lists for output price adjustment. Harvard recognizes that this approach will mean sometimes counting 2 distinct procedures performed on the same day as 1 claim day. As a result those days will be codes as having a higher price as opposed to greater quantity.

More detailed methods are described here:

• For inpatient facility claims, all claims coded as the same DRG on the same date of admission for the same person will be collapsed to 1 claim-day. There are no inpatient facility claims that are missing an associated DRG code.

• CPTs are used for inpatient professional, outpatient professional, and outpatient facility claims. There are three components paid

Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×

    for a CPT claim a work component, a practice expense and a malpractice component. If the service is provided in a facility (which is always the case for inpatient services and may be the case for outpatient services) the practice expense component is reduced and the facility gets paid separately (by DRG in the case of inpatient or CPT in the case of outpatient). We will collapse inpatient professional claims with the same enrollee, day, and procedure code into 1 claim-day observation.

• For outpatient claims we cannot identify if and how the professional and technical components are broken out, and therefore we will collapse outpatient claims with the same procedure code, enrollee, and day into 1 “claim-day” observation, thus rolling together the professional and facility components.

• Around 45,000 outpatient claims (14 percent of total medical spending in 2007) do not have an associated procedure code. For these claims, we apportion spending across all CPT claims that occurred on the same day for each enrollee based on the proportion of spending that each CPT represents on that day. For instance, if $100 lacked a procedure code, and on the same day we observe two CPTs: CPT “A” for $200 and CPT “B” $400, we apportion the $100 based on a 1/3 and 2/3 ratio, respectively. The new value for CPT “A” is $225, and CPT “B” is $475. We run this apportioning step before performing input or output price adjustments, and before imputing capitated claims.

HARVARD OUTPUT-PRICE ADJUSTMENT MEMORANDUM (10.05.12)

Background

The purpose of the output price adjustment is to eliminate the effect of different prices between locations. Harvard’s approach is to create a nationalized standard price for each procedure code and type of claim (inpatient DRG, inpatient CPT, and outpatient CPT) based on the national mean payment for each procedure per day it was rendered. This standard price is then applied back to each claim day of the same type. For example, we compute the mean spending per person per day for a specific code for computed tomography (CT) scan (conditional on being greater than zero for that person on that day). We then apply that price to each person day for the same CT code regardless of where they live or what was actually paid.

Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×

Trimming Before Calculating the National Mean Price

We do not trim claims other than those with spending less than or equal to zero. We experimented with trimming and found it made the decomposition into price and quantity effects difficult without substantially altering conclusions about aggregate variation.

Types of Claims Included

The output price adjustment is performed for all inpatient and outpatient claims with a procedure code. Claims that do not include a procedure code and that cannot be apportioned to other claims on the same day are left unadjusted. Capitated claim days are omitted when calculating means/ medians. Drug claims are also left unadjusted

Summing Procedure

After the spending is adjusted as described above, the adjusted spending amounts and residual unadjusted spending (drug claims and claims that are missing procedure code after the apportioning step) are summed across a person-year. This results in one output price adjusted value per person per year.

Zero-Dollar and Capitated Claims

We outline our overall approach to capitated claim-days in a separate memo. We will apply an output price adjustment value to all capitated claim days (even those with observed spending of $0). We will not apply an output price adjustment to non-capitated claim days that have $0 spending. This is because we believe capitated claim days with zero dollar spending generally represent procedures that occurred, while non-capitated claim days with zero dollar spending are likely corrections and do not represent actual services.

Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×

This page intentionally left blank.

Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×
Page 141
Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×
Page 142
Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×
Page 143
Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×
Page 144
Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×
Page 145
Suggested Citation:"Appendix E: Harvard University Price Adjustment Memorandums." Institute of Medicine. 2013. Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/18393.
×
Page 146
Next: Appendix F: Harvard Market Variables Memorandum »
Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography Get This Book
×
 Variation in Health Care Spending: Target Decision Making, Not Geography
Buy Paperback | $55.00 Buy Ebook | $44.99
MyNAP members save 10% online.
Login or Register to save!
Download Free PDF

Health care in the United States is more expensive than in other developed countries, costing $2.7 trillion in 2011, or 17.9 percent of the national gross domestic product. Increasing costs strain budgets at all levels of government and threaten the solvency of Medicare, the nation's largest health insurer. At the same time, despite advances in biomedical science, medicine, and public health, health care quality remains inconsistent. In fact, underuse, misuse, and overuse of various services often put patients in danger.

Many efforts to improve this situation are focused on Medicare, which mainly pays practitioners on a fee-for-service basis and hospitals on a diagnoses-related group basis, which is a fee for a group of services related to a particular diagnosis. Research has long shown that Medicare spending varies greatly in different regions of the country even when expenditures are adjusted for variation in the costs of doing business, meaning that certain regions have much higher volume and/or intensity of services than others. Further, regions that deliver more services do not appear to achieve better health outcomes than those that deliver less.

Variation in Health Care Spending investigates geographic variation in health care spending and quality for Medicare beneficiaries as well as other populations, and analyzes Medicare payment policies that could encourage high-value care. This report concludes that regional differences in Medicare and commercial health care spending and use are real and persist over time. Furthermore, there is much variation within geographic areas, no matter how broadly or narrowly these areas are defined. The report recommends against adoption of a geographically based value index for Medicare payments, because the majority of health care decisions are made at the provider or health care organization level, not by geographic units. Rather, to promote high value services from all providers, Medicare and Medicaid Services should continue to test payment reforms that offer incentives to providers to share clinical data, coordinate patient care, and assume some financial risk for the care of their patients.

Medicare covers more than 47 million Americans, including 39 million people age 65 and older and 8 million people with disabilities. Medicare payment reform has the potential to improve health, promote efficiency in the U.S. health care system, and reorient competition in the health care market around the value of services rather than the volume of services provided. The recommendations of Variation in Health Care Spending are designed to help Medicare and Medicaid Services encourage providers to efficiently manage the full range of care for their patients, thereby increasing the value of health care in the United States.

READ FREE ONLINE

  1. ×

    Welcome to OpenBook!

    You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

    Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

    No Thanks Take a Tour »
  2. ×

    Show this book's table of contents, where you can jump to any chapter by name.

    « Back Next »
  3. ×

    ...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

    « Back Next »
  4. ×

    Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

    « Back Next »
  5. ×

    Switch between the Original Pages, where you can read the report as it appeared in print, and Text Pages for the web version, where you can highlight and search the text.

    « Back Next »
  6. ×

    To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter.

    « Back Next »
  7. ×

    Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

    « Back Next »
  8. ×

    View our suggested citation for this chapter.

    « Back Next »
  9. ×

    Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

    « Back Next »
Stay Connected!