National Academies Press: OpenBook

Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment (1999)

Chapter: Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets

« Previous: Appendix B Sources of Physical and Valuation Data on Natural Resources and the Environment
Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×

Appendix C
Accounting for Forest Assets

While adjustment in an asset account is conceptually similar to net investment of ''made assets," it is more precise for forests to call the change in asset values "net accumulation" to reflect the fact that, even at constant prices, the asset value of a forest can either increase or decrease. Most generally, net accumulation is defined 1 as

where N(t) is the net accumulation in period t, and V(t) is the asset value in period t (present value of rents). As Hartwick and Hagemann (1993) have shown, net accumulation can also be written as:

where r = discount rate (or the difference between the nominal interest rate and the rate of growth of log prices, p is the price of logs, q(t) is the harvest level in period t, and C[q(t)] is total extraction costs. While these definitions are both general and precise, they are generally impossible to implement empirically: V(t + 1) cannot be directly observed in period t.

1  

This development is done in discrete time to reflect (1) the annual growth period of temperate and boreal forests that characterizes virtually the entire United States, and (2) the annual reporting period that is recommended for forest accounting.

Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×

Instead, economists infer the value of the asset from assumptions about intertemporal market equilibrium. Three cases have been examined.

The first is identical to the literature on nonrenewable resources, appropriately treating the exploitation of primary, old-growth forests as timber mining. Since it is generally uneconomic to replace primary forests with forests of a similarly old age, this analogy is not as odd as it might seem. Under these circumstances,

where C'[q(t)] is marginal extraction costs. This model of net accumulation (pure depreciation) is generally called the Hotelling model to emphasize the connection between mining old growth that will not be replaced and mining minerals that cannot be replaced.

While the Hotelling model may be appropriate for the case of pure depreciation, it misses several important aspects of the forest sector. An alternative approach is transition models, which account in part for these problems by recognizing that forest growth offsets harvests. Assuming constant prices and a forest inventory recognized only by total net growth, this model suggests that net accumulation is

where g(t) is the net forest growth in period t.

By recognizing forest growth, such a formulation improves on the ordinary Hotelling approach, but still suffers the defects of (1) ignoring endogenous price changes in the sector and (2) characterizing the forest only by net growth and not its more complex underlying age-class structure. Economic theory suggests that once the transition between old- and second-growth forests is complete, timber prices will stabilize and the economic return to holding forests will arise solely from forest growth. Vincent (1997) has developed the appropriate measures of net accumulation for optimally managed second-growth forests. Depreciation associated with the harvests equals

where h is values per unit area, v(τ) is the timber yield at age τ, and τ* is the economically optimal rotation age. Accumulation associated with the growth of subrotation-age forests is

Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×

Net accumulation is simply the sum of unit-area depreciation or accumulation weighted by the area in the particular age class:

where A(t,τ) is the area in age-class τ in period t. Note that if A(t,τ) = ΣA(τ)/τ* for all τ (the so-called "normal forest" with an equal area in each age class), then N(t) = 0. This approach improves upon both the Hotelling and transition approaches. It assumes that forest owners cut their trees at the economically optimal time and that timber prices are in intertemporal market equilibrium.

The three cases discussed above require assumptions of intertemporal price equilibrium, optimal management, and constant prices and costs. These are strong assumptions. With the data that exist for U.S. forests, it is possible to develop a practical approach for measuring timber accumulation that improves upon the methods used in most countries and requires less restrictive assumptions.

Ideally, one would like transaction data on a representative sample of timberland. Because timberland is an extremely heterogenous product traded in dispersed markets, assembling such data is quite difficult. 2 It is therefore necessary to compute V(t) and V(t + 1) directly and to estimate net accumulation using equation (C.1). One possible approach, following Vincent (1997), begins by summing per-acre values weighted by area across all age classes (subscripts for other important value descriptors, such as region, ownership, species, and site quality, are suppressed for ease of reading).

where T is actual cutting age, p(t) is net price (stumpage price), pl (t) is bare-land value, and Cs(t) is full rotation management costs in period t.

2  

The National Council of Real Estate Fiduciaries maintains a database on the value of some industrial-grade timberland in three regions of the United States: the Pacific coast, the south, and the northeast. While these data are useful for measuring the return on timberland assets, they have severe limitations for present purposes. First, they reflect industrial-grade timberland, a category of timberland that probably covers no more than 20 percent of the total area of U.S. forestland. Second, the data generally do not reflect actual property transactions, but rather appraised values. Third, the number of properties in the sample, especially in the northeast, is small, and the data do not cover the north central or inland west regions at all.

Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×

Figure C-1

Valuation of Forest Stands of Differing Ages.

The above are the basic valuation equations for forests of different age classes. Figure C-1 shows the approach graphically. The value of an acre of age-class τ timber is simply the value of the timber at the harvest age T (which may or may not be the economically optimal harvest age), discounted by the number of years until harvest. Note that p(t) in this formulation is net price, not price gross of extraction costs. This definition is used because the net price (called the stumpage price) is commonly recorded in forestry. While net prices differ across regions and among species, some evidence suggests that within a region, extraction costs may be constant (Adams, 1997). In this formulation, net rent = A(t,T)v(T)p(t) and is already accounted for in the National Income and Product Accounts for marketed timber. If desired, net accumulation can be divided into separate revaluation, growth, and depletion accounts in the usual way.

How would such an approach be implemented? The forest inventory and analysis work of the U.S. Department of Agriculture's Forest Service maintains data on A(t,τ), v(τ), T, and Cs(t) by eight regions in the United States, ownership, and site quality; unfortunately, the data on the national forests are not as comprehensive as those on private and other public lands. The Forest Service's ATLAS model is designed to update the inventory on an annual basis and to project it into the future. Data on p(t) by region and species (or species group) are available from the Forest

Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×

Service (the value of timber harvested in a year, or so called "cut prices") and from commercial price reports for some regions.

The primary difficulty with this valuation approach is selecting the discount rate (r) to be used. Similar difficulties arise in minerals accounting when the net present value approach is introduced. No valuation method escapes this difficulty, except with strong and unrealistic assumptions about intertemporal price paths. A practical approach is to reestimate the discount rate periodically on the basis of an asset pricing model for timberland. The discount rate is then treated in the same manner as timber prices, with a separate revaluation account to reflect changes in the discount rate.

Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×
Page 202
Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×
Page 203
Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×
Page 204
Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×
Page 205
Suggested Citation:"Appendix C Accounting for Forest Assets." National Research Council. 1999. Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/6374.
×
Page 206
Next: Appendix D Glossary »
Nature's Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment Get This Book
×
Buy Hardback | $55.00 Buy Ebook | $43.99
MyNAP members save 10% online.
Login or Register to save!
Download Free PDF

In order to really see the forest, what's the best way to count the trees? Understanding how the economy interacts with the environment has important implications for policy, regulatory, and business decisions. How should our national economic accounts recognize the increasing interest in and importance of the environment?

Nature's Numbers responds to concerns about how the United States should make these measurements. The book recommends how to incorporate environmental and other non-market measures into the nation's income and product accounts.

The panel explores alternative approaches to environmental accounting, including those used in other countries, and addresses thorny issues such as how to measure the stocks of natural resources and how to value non-market activities and assets. Specific applications to subsoil minerals, forests, and clean air show how the general principles can be applied.

The analysis and insights provided in this book will be of interest to economists, policymakers, environmental advocates, economics faculty, businesses based on natural resources, and managers concerned with the role of the environment in our economic affairs.

  1. ×

    Welcome to OpenBook!

    You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

    Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

    No Thanks Take a Tour »
  2. ×

    Show this book's table of contents, where you can jump to any chapter by name.

    « Back Next »
  3. ×

    ...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

    « Back Next »
  4. ×

    Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

    « Back Next »
  5. ×

    Switch between the Original Pages, where you can read the report as it appeared in print, and Text Pages for the web version, where you can highlight and search the text.

    « Back Next »
  6. ×

    To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter.

    « Back Next »
  7. ×

    Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

    « Back Next »
  8. ×

    View our suggested citation for this chapter.

    « Back Next »
  9. ×

    Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

    « Back Next »
Stay Connected!